Econometrics applies regression analysis to economics, adding methods developed for specific problems. This article documents the distinct aspects of econometrics.
Econometrics is concerned with the measurement of economic relations. Measuring marginal effect is the goal of most empirical economics research. Examples of economic relations include the relation between earnings and education, work experience; expenditure on a commodity and household income; price and attributes of a good or service; output of firm and inputs of labor, capital, materials; inflation and unemployment rates.
A regression model is often referred to as a reduced form regression, if the focus is on the prediction of outcome given predictors rather than the causal interpretation of the model parameters. Models for causal inference include simultaneous equations models, potential outcome model, etc.
See also Applied Econometrics.
Linear regression model (LM):
\[ Y \mid \mathbf{X} \sim \text{Normal}(\mathbf{X}' \beta, \sigma^2) \]
Terminology:
If there are multiple outcomes, the model is called general linear model. If there's only one predictor, the model is called simple linear regression, to distinguish from (multiple) linear regression. The residual consists of omitted or unobservable variables (latent variables); often includes a constant/intercept term.
While many observables in social sciences have heavy tailed distribution, the distributions of their logarithms are typically well behaved. For example, in econometrics, monetary variables such as earnings are often log-transformed. Transformation can also improve homogeneity of variances. (An alternative technique is weighted least squares.) But interpretations of the two are not the same.
Model assumptions explained:
Multicollinearity (also collinearity) refers to the presence of highly correlated subsets of predictors. Perfect multicollinearity means a subset of predictors are linearly dependent.
Violations of the Exogeneity Assumption that still satisfy the weaker \( \mathbb{E}(u_i|X_i) = 0 \) only occur with dependent data structures. However, it is often hard to assess whether the Exogeneity Assumption is satisfied, even if the model does not explicitly imply a violation.
The Spherical Residuals Assumption is generally too strong, because data in economics and many other fields commonly have heteroskedasticity, autocorrelation (aka serial correlation in time-series data), or intraclass correlation (in clustered data).
For most purposes, the Conditional Normality Assumption is not necessary (optional).
In macroeconomics, R-squared is often very high; 0.8 or higher is not unusual. In microeconomics, it is typically very low, with 0.1 not unusual. The reason might be that the number of observations in macroeconomics is often much lower (e.g., 25 OECD countries) than in micro-econometrics (e.g., 10,000 households), while the number of predictors is not that different.
Seeing regression as the approximation of regression function, R-squared does not have to be very close to one for model justification, distinct from practice in physics and mechanics experiments. This is because we're only considering average effect, rather than elimination of error term.
MLE (for classification models), GMM
Asymptotic Inference: Asymptotic distribution of regression estimators.
Observational data (case control sampling) vs. experimental data (design of experiments, DOE).
Model and estimator are in some way analogous to simulation and estimation of random processes.